Pages

Friday, January 28, 2011

Trade-based money laundering on the rise


The term ‘money laundering’ is said to have originated from mafia ownership of Laundromats in the US. Gangsters there were earning huge sums in cash by extortion, prostitution, gambling and bootleg liquor. They needed to show a legitimate source for these monies. 

Money launderers now resort to the use of apparently legitimate commercial transactions to camouflage their laundering activities. There has been an increasing amount of interest of late in commodity trade-based money laundering. Deception is the heart of money laundering. This is being increasingly used to move the cash proceeds through a process by which the transactions appear very genuine.
 

Commodity trade-based money laundering has been growing as an alternative remittance system that allows illegal and unaccounted money with an opportunity to earn and move the proceeds disguised as legitimate trade. Increasingly, the domestic commodity trade is being used for bribing politically exposed persons (PEP) and government officials. 

In India, sometimes the task is achieved by purchasing commodities (above the market price - ‘placement’) from a so-called genuine supplier (often a conduit of PEP or relatives of officials), transferring them to another entity where the commodity is sold (‘layering’) and the proceeds are remitted to the intended recipient (‘integration’). The
 large companies (with bigger reputation and brands) sometimes use the channels to oblige the powerful. Since the size is often small compared to other genuine transactions, this never gets discovered. 

Trade flow volumes have increased significantly as a result of globalisation. An Exchangebased transaction in India is also showing double digit growth. Such large trade flows and paper trade growth provide ample channel, through which transactions can be obscured due to the presence of complex transactional
 structures and co-mingling of illicit funds with the cash flows of a legitimate business. 

Global trade is used by larger criminal and terrorist organizations to move value around the world through complex and sometimes confusing documentation that is frequently associated with legitimate trade transactions. The illicit trades are often blended in with legitimate ones, which make them difficult to single out and the source of their funding hard to trace. The scope and prevalence of the practice is tough to determine with any precision, but it is clearly on the rise. Values have moved through this process by false-invoicing, over invoicing and under-invoicing commodities that are transacted in the domestic market (no more restricted to imported or exported commodities).
 

Relaxed oversights by domestic authorities along with weak procedures to inspect goods and register legal entities provide sufficient opportunity for such activities. Moreover, inadequate information technology systems
 and lack of adequate coordination and cooperation between regulators often lead to misuse by the launderers. 

As money laundering methods become complex and sophisticated, it is necessary that agencies, authorities, investigators and prosecutors alike should equip themselves with the evolving knowledge of money laundering typologies. Instead of just issuing instructions to abide by PMLA (Prevention of Money Laundering Act, 2002), the regulators must equip themselves with the market-based forensic knowledge of such activities.
 

Investigations have shown that one of the most effective ways to identify instances of trade-based money laundering is through trade data for anomalies that would only be apparent by examining both sides of a trade transaction. Sometimes commodities being traded do not match the business involved and on other occasions, false reporting provides adequate indicators of trade-based money laundering.
 

Friday, January 21, 2011

More time needed to clear confusion on warehouse receipts

Two terminologies — commodities demat and negotiable warehouse receipt — in the commodities market has created more confusion in the last seven years than in any participatory facilitation. 

The jargons have led the market to a state of confusion because these are perceived more as “insurance policies” underwritten by an exchange and the warehouseman (as applicable) for the users rather than instruments of facilitation.
 

Brokers and investors are confused
 about “commodity demat” as they often draw a parallel to the seamless stock market functioning. In case of commodity demat, the mere act of recordkeeping in the electronic form has not conferred the qualifications of “security” on the commodity. The statute of “security” to the demat commodity has remained elusive under the Depository Act. Therefore, the funding of a demat commodity has conferred an inferior legal protection on the lender when compared to the demat funding of stocks. 

On the other hand, a warehouse receipt (WHR) is not negotiable under the common law. A WHR is an instrument issued by a warehouseman, reciting receipt of certain goods therein described and evidencing the contract between the parties along with the details of warehousing. What is being envisaged (however, not yet grasped) under the WDRA Act, 2007, is to confer on the document in a certain way the same sort of limited and peculiar negotiability which is possessed by a bill of lading.
 

A WHR can only be an evidence to the title of the goods and not a promise to pay while a “negotiable instrument” means paper evidencing a debt ultimately reducible to money and not calling for the delivery of other property.
 

The law regarding the document of title
 is trying to borrow the feature of negotiability from the law of negotiable instruments but it must always be remembered that the two classes of instruments — negotiable instruments on one hand and documents of title on the other — must in certain respects be different and be governed as they are today by entirely different bodies of law. 

The negotiable instrument is a promise to pay or an order to pay money while a document of title calls for delivery by a bailee (warehouseman) of certain particular goods. It is better to keep this thought
 in mind that a warehouse receipt is a document of title not a negotiable instrument and that there is a separate body of law governing each. 

If at all, WHR becomes negotiable, it will pass greater freedom from hand to hand chiefly by the reason of the fact that the transferee thereof does not need to notify the bailee (warehouseman) of his acquisition of title while a transferee of an assignable document of title (WHR) acquires no rights against the bailee except by giving notice.

By assigning negotiability on WHR will not provide the document with a status of “negotiable instrument” but can be referred as a “negotiable document of title”. It is going to take a while before the cloud of confusion is removed and we see a clear blue sky on the commodity horizon in India. 

People asking questions lost in confusion,
Well I tell them there’s no problem, Only solutions,
I’m just sitting here watching the wheels go round and round,
I really love to watch them roll, No longer riding on the merry-go-round, 

— John Lennon’s ‘Watching the Wheels’
 

Friday, January 14, 2011

Corporates’ farm land buy a cause of serious concern

When missionaries came to Africa,
They had the Bible and we had the land
They said, “Let us pray” We closed our eyes.
When we opened them
We had the Bible and they had the land.
 — Bishop Desmond Tutu

AGRICULTURAL land around the world has become a new magnet for speculative financial flows. ‘Efficiency, wastage reduction and supply chain bottlenecks’ have become latest gospels to grab land. Soaring farmland values have generated new investment vehicles and increased participation in existing vehicles by institutional investors.

With food prices rising again, interest in farmland is on the rise. The private investors believe the trend will continue, given that the world needs to increase food production by 70% by 2050 to feed a rising and wealthier population.

The influx of financial investment into agricultural land is global. A few years back, agrifood giant Louis Dreyfus Commodities raised $65 million for Aclyx Agro Ltd, its vehicle established to buy, operate and sell land in Latin America (chiefly Brazil). The influx gained notoriety after an attempt in 2008 by South Korea’s Daewoo Logistics to secure a large chunk of land in Madagascar for a very low price and vague promises of investment.

In India, land banks are also being created. Driven by the huge opportunities, Indian corporations too are aggressively expanding into the agriculture and retail sector (both with the ultimate objective of land bank). In a few states, pitch for APMC land by a few corporates has already been made in the name of “modernization”.

The cause for concern is that this is happening without a proper regulatory framework and lack of comprehensive understanding of the likely impact on agriculture in general. Agriculture, land use, real estate, tax and labour policies and laws are being changed to facilitate the entry and growth of big corporate agencies into agriculture and retail.

Under the financial imperatives, firms in the food processing and agricultural service sector have essentially become bundle of assets to be deployed or redeployed depending on the short-run rates of returns that can be earned. Investors in the food processing and agricultural services sectors are now demanding rates of return equal to those obtainable in global financial and stock markets at the rates unthinkable even a decade ago. In the absence of a high operating margin, the land valuation game is being played.

Agricultural service sector has already moved into the “high cost” trajectory. Prices of agricultural products are in a long-term upward trend due to factors like increasing land cost and high input cost (e.g. fertilizer price driven by crude). It is likely to go up even further, with further pumping of private funds into agriculture, food processing industry, warehousing and agriculture infrastructure. Productivity continues to grow but wages no longer keep pace with profits and productivity. Focus has shifted from increasing productivity to deployment and distribution.

While we don’t have the luxury of philosophizing about food, the bottleneck in food supply chain is the latest whipping boy of the government to be blamed for the price rise. Under the grab of the supply chain bottlenecks, large investments are likely to be approved in the coming months which will benefit a selected few with incentives (subsidies) and the land bank creation opportunities. First it was the floods of North and now it is the food price rise which is being cited as the reason for the need for increased investment.

While there is a need ‘it is only going to benefit a selected few with policy incentives. Mark Twain once said “buy land, they’re not making it any more” and it seems that corporate and private investors share his view. 

Friday, January 7, 2011

Latest surveillance systems a must to check price spikes

Every now and then, it is fashionable to talk of market manipulation and how some traders (hoarders in Indian context) have “rigged” the market to favour themselves and to fleece the average investor or consumer. 

We are now witnessing with a yo-yo like price movement in the precious metal market - a playback of crude spike of 2007 but this time it is silver. You are bound to hear of three types of talk: 
•We have consumed nearly all the silver in the world
•We continue to consume more than we mine 
•Never before have conditions like today ever existed 

Let’s break down a logical fallacy. If we assume that the presence of market manipulation in commodities makes it impossible to forecast price trends (or at least makes it impossible to follow basic trends through a reasoned strategy), we have to assume that dabbling in any commodity category is a waste of time and money and should be completely avoided. Why is this true? Any asset worth investing at any given time is under manipulation. That’s right: manipulation is actually a normal phenomenon without which a smooth-functioning, trending market environment would be impossible. 

Market manipulation is a practice in which people engage in activities which interfere with the normal operations of the market. Many nations have only a loose definition of market manipulation because it is sometimes difficult to point specific manipulative behaviors but people can still track manipulative activities and see the influence manipulation can have on the market. These practices are illegal in many regions of the world, although sometimes it can be difficult to distinguish between normal activities and market manipulation. 

This brings us to a basic question: if manipulation is normal and the regulator exists only in times of normalcy, do we actually need a commodity regulator? 

In its 36-year history, even a regulator like the US Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) has successfully prosecuted and won only one manipulation case in the commodities markets. In the past, CFTC had to prove that an individual intended to manipulate prices and evidence was often difficult to find through e-mails or phone calls. It also had to show that the person had the market power to move the price of a commodity and that the trader caused a price in the market that otherwise would not have occurred. 

The recently-passed Dodd Frank Act has changed some of these in the US. The CFTC will now only have to show that a trader acted in a manner which had the potential to disrupt the market, making it easier to prove the case. The Dodd-Frank Act also requires the CFTC to ban certain trading practices that include “banging the close” and “spoofing.” 

“Banging the close” refers to the practice of acquiring a substantial position leading up to the closing period, followed by offsetting the position before the end of trading for the purpose of attempting to manipulate prices. “Spoofing” is where a trader makes bids or offers but cancels them before execution (widely prevalent practice in India). 

In India, we do not have legislative support against price manipulators and the controlling systems are also not pro-active information-based. 

Market intelligence and price monitoring are being rigorously pursued in a large number of countries. Our systems are often police-like (with raids following a price rise). The monitoring systems are reactive rather than price surveillance-based. A transformation from a reactive to a surveillance-based system shall require efforts and commitment, both at the central and state levels. 

Internal compliance and surveillance teams of ministries should arm themselves with tools and metrics that are at least as rigorous as those used by technology-savvy regulators. Finding the appropriate mix of risk-based, price-based and activity-based screeners are essential. 

For Indian regulators, it may not reasonable and feasible to focus on every market and every trader every day. However a risk-based approach to price data screening can increase the likelihood that compliance and surveillance teams are alerted to potential issues and reduce the surprises of price manipulations. 

Thursday, December 30, 2010

Commex regulation, governance a tough balancing act

Regulatory and supervisory responsibilities in commodities continue to remain divided among multiple regulators. 


The weaknesses of FCRA, ECA, WDRA, multiple state APMC acts and individual commodity acts have important implications for governance and stakeholder protection. And, having several regulators is costly and inefficient, especially in a country like ours. 


While the strengthening of the regulatory structure in commodity markets is important, the governance structure of the exchanges cannot be ignored. In various discussions on the commodity sector, one question that does not get the attention it merits is: on whose behalf should the commodity exchange be governed. 


Of course, conventional wisdom is that a company (or a commex in this case) is governed on behalf of the shareholders. In fact, among the various shareholders of any company (including commexes), shareholders tend to be the least loyal — selling holdings at the first sign of trouble (at times even throwing them out of their premises). Second, it is incorrect that a regulator-approved independent board (along with regulator’s own nominee) protects the interest of the shareholders most of whom have bought shares at a throw-away price. 


Commex governance is closely linked with the type of investors and the performance parameters that controlling investors establish (turnover verses price discovery). As such, it has to manage a profound conflict of interest between market making and market restraining. In a business that exists hypocritically for the “benefit of farmers”, the question then is, do we need a different breed of investors for the commex business for exchange governance? Should it be classified ”social business”? 


As the traditional role of the broker as conduit between investor and exchange is increasingly rendered obsolete by electronic communication technology, the trading function will become increasingly disintermediated. Any exchange business with a long-term view has to engage with brokers and the well-being of an exchange business lies in the wellbeing of its brokers. If commexes have a short horizon, then they engage in market making, employee poaching and at times a few of these brokers become the stakeholders in exchange. 


The quality and orientation of the investments that are flowing in the commex is not “patient capital”. The equity of banks and financial institutions is in the form of “sleeping capital” and do not add any value with its nonparticipatory stance. Thus the anchor investor may have the capacity to manoeuvre the norms of exchange governance with impunity but within the ambit of “regulation”. It is this misapprehension that lies at the heart of many concerns. Regulatory failures are inevitable any time as self-regulatory obligations imposed on an exchange are in conflict with the commercial interests of the exchange’s owners. Such commercial interests are more powerful for a mutualised exchange than for a demutualised one.
If commodity exchanges have to succeed, they have to figure out whether they want to be there, not only the next couple of years, but for the next century. The shorter the horizon investors come with, the quicker is the exit route.

Friday, December 24, 2010

Ad-hoc price control efforts are disastrous in long run

An old debate continues: whether “high onion prices are good or bad” and the answer is, “it depends on whether the poor are selling or buying.” High prices benefit farmers who are net sellers, and hurt consumers in urban areas. Low prices have the opposite effect. In each case, the net effect depends on the balance between who is able to manoeuvre the policy in his favour. 

High prices do not mean high price realisation by onion farmers. It only shows a better information arbitrage by a selected few while the ‘babus’ remain the most ill informed in times of impending crisis. Price instability is a general feature of agricultural markets. The current onion price crisis has highlighted the vulnerability of inter-ministerial communication or rather the lack of it. 

Too many cooks spoil the broth is nowhere more apparent than the current onion crisis. A coordinated effort between four ministries —ministry of consumer affairs (dealing with controlling price), ministry of commerce (dealing in trade, exports & imports), ministry of earth sciences (weather forecasting) and agriculture ministry — would have yielded better price-control mechanisms. 

The architecture of decision-making at the ministerial level does not seem to be sensitive to the issue that the government’s role in a free market economy is not to bring down the price at every spike of a commodity but to create a consistent policy environment where such surprises become minimum. The executive arm is still stuck in a time-wrap when the state was supposed to control prices for the consumers (the middle class in general). 

Ad-hoc trade policy interventions such as export ban and import subsidies have always been harmful in the long run. The Left politicians (as usual) are making noise to ban forward market without knowing the fact that onions are not traded on the futures. Hopefully, they shall come better prepared the next time or should they start asking to ban oil futures on NYMEX/ICE for petrol price rise. It was also amusing to see an Opposition politician (from my school), who has refined taste for good things in life, talking about ‘aam admi'. 

What is perhaps most telling about the price increases of onions is the negative impact of their extreme volatility. Both high and low prices have winners and losers but volatility hurts everyone except traders and speculators. Stable and remunerative prices should be the goal. That will attract investment into agriculture and bring long-term benefits beyond the short-run effects. 

In the US, the ban on trading of futures contracts in onions was passed on August 28, 1958, and remains in effect as of 2010. The studies by Holbrook Working and later by Roger Gray (Stanford 1963), Aaron C. Johnson (1976) have concluded that onion prices had been less volatile during the years when the contract was active. 

While the politicians continue to make the right noise about the failures and ability of the government to control prices, the real issues of productivity, export policy, weather forecasting in a coordinated fashion remains a dream (in spite of huge investments). Past adhoc efforts on stabilising prices at a certain level by some individual countries have generally been unsuccessful all over the world. 

Price spikes in the times of market economy are going to remain chronic. Should the government continue to intervene every time during the price spike on tax payers’ money, that would be to rob Peter to pay Paul. 

Friday, December 17, 2010

Shift commodity risk management to finance teams

What is the right price for cotton, coffee, copper and crude? Not even a soothsayer will try to take a bet on this. Analysts will produce gigabytes of reports and charts, debating whether the market is likely to go up or down and not whether the price is correct or not. 

Except for occasional cases, most of the corporates in India do not have commodity hedge plan in place for their manufacturing activities. These large corporates have not been able to come to terms with the fact that they are not the most efficient buyers anymore. Often corporate hedge plans end with an appointment of a consultant who gives a beautiful report which never gets read, let alone be implemented. 

Managers resort to statements like “our company policy does not allow hedge programme”. Some of these large companies even arm-twist the government to change trade policies as evident from the recent case of cotton (textile companies) and a few years ago on iron ore exports (steel producers).

The creation of commodity indices and exchange-traded funds saw the amount of asset investment swelling internationally. This has greatly increased the volatility. Increased volatility has lead to riskier strategies. The ripple effect has caused even more volatile commodity prices in India, leading to shorter lead times between the price spike and the price paid by end users. 

Some of the manufacturing companies had attempted hedge programmes when the prices were high only to abandon them after a few brain-storming sessions.

Everything goes on a backburner and a flurry of activities recur only when the quarterly numbers are analysed.Somehow, the annual budgeting has become a mere ritual without much understanding of the price behavior of raw material cost and energy cost. 

The issue of whether or not to hedge commodity price risk continues to baffle many corporations. At the heart of the confusion are misconceptions about risk, concerns about the cost of hedging and fears about reporting a loss on derivative transactions. A lack of familiarity with hedging tools and strategies compounds this confusion. Corporate risk managers also face the difficult challenge of getting hedging tools (such as derivatives) approved by the company’s board of directors. 

A few years ago, when an Indian engineering giant reported losses on the hedge books, the analysts on electronic media went about giving soundbites without the slightest of understanding that the company may have made up by having a lower cost of raw materials on the physical side.

Many companies handle commodity price risk management through their purchasing departments but now treasurers are seeing the direct impact of commodity prices on profit and loss. It is a cost input. They can clearly see the impact on their need for funding and liquidity. Therefore, commodity risk should be managed by the treasury as a financial risk like any other.

Putting commodity risk management in the hands of a finance team may be an important first step but it is just the start of the process of building an effective hedging strategy. There has been an exponential growth in companies’ exposure to commodity prices and therefore the need to hedge is more acute.